|
|
|
| 1 | 2
| 3
| |
|
COLUMBIA FORUM
Fifty Years of Empty Promises
Hispanics are on track to become the largest minority group
in the United States during the next decade and a full quarter of
the population by 2050. In Harvest of Empire: A History of
Latinos in America (Viking, $27), New York Daily News
columnist Juan González, who entered with the
Class of 1968, explores the origins and implications of the
explosion of Latino peoples and cultures in the U.S. In this
excerpt, González, who has been named one of the country's 100
most influential Hispanics by Hispanic Business and received
a 1998 George Polk Journalism Award for Commentary, examines the
consequences of free trade for Latin America.
North Americans at first ventured into Mexico, the Caribbean
and Central America during the nineteenth century to buy up land
and build massive transportation projects: Vanderbilt's Nicaraguan
Transit Company, Minor Keith's Central American Railroad,
Aspinwall's Panama Railroad, for example. By the early twentieth
century, the main methods of exploitation had shifted to extracting
raw materials - bananas, sugar, coffee, oil - and to financing the
operations of Latin American governments. The region grew to be so
important that by 1914, U.S. companies had $416 million in direct
investments in Mexico alone, the highest of any country in the
world, and Latin America overall accounted for nearly half of all
U.S. foreign investment in the world.
The
period after World War II brought a third shift, as U.S. apparel,
then electronics, plastics, and chemical companies, started closing
down factories at home and reopening them abroad. That offshore
production is at the heart of the free trade model the United
States has promoted and perfected in Latin America....
As
quickly as industrial plants were shuttered in the Northeast and
Midwest, scores of shiny new industrial parks and factory towns,
usually called free trade zones (FTZs) or export processing zones
(EPZs), sprang up south of the border. By 1992, there were more
than 200 of these zones in Mexico and the Caribbean Basin. They
housed more than 3,000 assembly plants, employed 735,000 workers,
and produced $14 billion in annual exports to the United
States.
These free trade zones were allowed to operate as virtual
sovereign enclaves within the host countries, routinely ignoring
the few local labor and environmental laws that existed. Inside the
zones, child labor was reborn and the most basic rights of workers
trampled. As agricultural production in many Latin American
countries fell under the sway of foreign agribusiness, millions of
Latin America's young people abandoned the countryside to find work
in or near the zones. But the cities to which the migrants moved
lacked infrastructures of roads, sewage systems, housing and
schools to sustain the surge in population. Worker shantytowns
sprang up overnight, and with the shantytowns and the factories
came industrial pollution, untreated human waste, disease, crime -
in short, a public health nightmare.
Thus, free trade, which was supposed to stabilize the economies
of the countries involved, has actually made conditions worse, and
the free trade zones, instead of providing Latin Americans with
living wage jobs, have probably fueled massive Latin American
emigration to the United States.
Typically, the young Latin American worker from the countryside
arrives in the local city and finds work in a free trade zone in
factories now commonly known as maquiladoras or maquilas. There,
the worker is trained in rudimentary industrial skills -the rigors
of assembly production, the discipline of time, the necessity for
obedience to instructions. At night, the worker begins studying
English in the scores of private language schools that abound in
the new urban environment. He or she becomes immersed in American
shows on the newly bought television - maquila workers in
Honduras are more likely to own a television (67 percent) than
non-maquila workers (60 percent); in fact, they are more
likely to own a television than a stove (49 percent) or a
refrigerator (24 percent). Each day, the worker devours the
Spanish-language magazines and newspapers that are easily available
in the cities and which glorify life in the United States. The
worker quickly learns she can earn ten times the salary she gets in
the maquila doing the same job in a factory across the
border. Eventually, filled with her new consciousness and disgusted
with her dead-end shantytown existence, the worker saves up the
money to pay a coyote and risks the trip to El Norte.
The
term "free trade" seems innocuous at first glance. Who could be
against the idea that nations should seek the maximum freedom to
trade with each other? Or that increased trade will bring with it
increased prosperity? Unfortunately, the history of most major
industrialized nations is just the opposite. None of them practiced
free trade during their early period of economic growth. Instead,
they used high tariffs to protect their domestic industries from
foreign competition, often engaging in tariff wars against
rivals.
"In
the early days, when British industry was still at a disadvantage,
an Englishman caught exporting raw wool was sentenced to lose his
right hand, and if he repeated the sin he was hanged," Uruguayan
journalist Eduardo Galeano reminds us.
Only
when England gained a decided advantage over all other countries in
world commerce did its government begin advocating free trade in
the nineteenth century. During the early days of Latin American
independence, England used the slogan to justify bullying the new
criollo governments. In the 1850s, for instance, British and
French warships sailed up the Rio Paraná to force the
protectionist government of Argentine leader Juan Manuel de Rosas
to open his country's prospering market to British bankers and
traders. Eventually, the British concentrated on controlling the
South American market, ceding control over most of the Caribbean
region to the United States.
In
our own country, Congress pursued protectionist policies throughout
the post-Civil War period, an era of extraordinary industrial
growth for the nation. "In every year from 1862 to 1911, the
average [U.S.] duty on all imports exceeded 20 percent...[and] in
forty-six of those fifty years...[it] exceeded 40 percent," notes
economist Alfred Eckes, who served on the International Trade
Commission under President Reagan. Germany pursued a similar
protectionist policy during its nineteenth-century industrial
expansion. Not surprisingly, both the German and the U.S. economies
experienced higher growth rates during that century than did
England, the era's main proponent of free trade.
Despite the historical record, most neoliberal economists in
the advanced industrial nations continue to praise the fall of
tariffs and the growth of free trade during the past few decades.
They contrast the new open global marketplace to the "bad old days"
of the 1970s, when Third World governments resorted to high tariffs
to protect their own fledgling industries, a strategy called import
substitution.
But
does expanded commerce automatically spur an increase in wealth, as
the free traders say? And just who are the main beneficiaries of
today's surge in international trading?
Free
trade proponents would have us believe this unfettered commerce is
occurring between millions of businessmen in scores of countries
and that the money changing hands is creating more and better-paid
workers, who then have more money to consume, which, in turn, means
that markets expand. But the reality is quite different. Two-thirds
of all the trade in the world today is between multinational
corporations, and one-third of it represents multinational
corporations trading with their own foreign subsidiaries! A General
Motors plant in Matamoros, for example, moves parts and finished
cars between itself and the parent company in the United States; or
Zenith ships machinery to expand one of its twelve assembly plants
operating in Reynosa. Between 1982 and 1995, exports of U.S.
multinational corporations more than doubled, but the portion of
those exports that represented intracompany trading more than
tripled. As a result of this enormous expansion of multinationals,
the largest private traders and employers in Mexico today are not
Mexican firms but U.S. corporations.
Furthermore, if free trade leads to greater prosperity, why has
economic inequality soared and poverty deepened in virtually every
Third World country that adopted neoliberal free trade policies?
According to the United Nations, the 225 richest people in the
world had a net worth in 1997 equal to the income of 2.5 billion
people, 47 percent of the world's population.
Latin America now suffers from the most uneven distribution of
wealth in its history. Before the 1980s, Latin Americans generally
protected their domestic industries through heavy government
ownership, high tariffs, and import substitution. Mexico pursued
that policy from 1940 to 1980, and during that time, it averaged
annual growth rates of more than 6 percent, with both manufacturing
output and real wages for industrial workers growing consistently.
But then came the debt crisis of the 1980s. Along with other Latin
American countries, Mexico was gradually pressured by
U.S.-controlled international financial institutions to adopt
neoliberal, free trade policies. Those policies included selling
public assets and increasing exports to pay down its debt. Between
1982 and 1992, the Mexican government sold off eleven hundred of
fifteen hundred state-owned companies and privatized more than
eighteen banks. This fire sale, instead of bringing prosperity,
only deepened the chasm between rich and poor, as a new crop of
Mexican billionaires emerged, real wages plummeted, and 200,000
Mexicans lost their jobs.
From
HARVEST OF EMPIRE: A HISTORY OF LATINOS IN AMERICA by Juan
González. Copyright © Juan González, 2000. Used by
permission.
|
| 1 | 2
| 3
| |
|
|
|
|